Statistics
| Branch: | Revision:

root / chapter3.tex @ 28:be66d105f0cb

History | View | Annotate | Download (29.9 kB)

1
\chapter{Overview of Literature in IT Governance}
2
\label{chapter:3}
3

    
4
The importance of \ac{it} governance has been widely acknowledged in the
5
academic and professional literature, especially with regards to the
6
private sector. The corporate scandals of Enron and other US-based
7
companies raised the level of regulation and tightened corporate
8
governance in order to protect investors and ensure fiscal
9
accountability. Increased significance was similarly attributed to \ac{it}
10
governance, which is the focus of this chapter. Research has found
11
that effective \ac{it} governance enhances competitiveness and business
12
value \cite{WeillRoss2004b}. There is debate, however, as to how this
13
can be best operationalised. The following sections will provide an
14
overview of the literature on the nature, forms and mechanisms of \ac{it}
15
governance. Current research in the main areas will be discussed,
16
together with the latest empirical findings.
17

    
18
\section{Defining IT Governance}
19

    
20
As a result of research developing in different areas, scholars and
21
professional bodies have suggested many useful definitions. There
22
seems to be general consensus as to how \ac{it} governance has come to
23
be interpreted, although the focus is slightly different between
24
studies.
25

    
26
Sambamurthy and Zmud \cite{SambamurthyZmud2000} define \ac{it}
27
governance as ``an organisation's \ac{it}-related authority pattern''.
28
The authors suggest research should understand the ``organising logic
29
for the \ac{it} function'' which they define as ``the managerial
30
rationale for designing and evolving specific organisational
31
arrangements in response to an enterprise's environmental and
32
strategic imperatives''. Building on this work, Schwarz and Hirschheim
33
\cite{Schwarz2003} refer to \ac{it} governance as ``the \ac{it}
34
related structures or architectures (and associated authority pattern)
35
implemented to successfully accomplish (\ac{it} imperative) activities
36
in response to an enterprise's environmental and strategic
37
imperatives''.
38

    
39
In another strand of research, Weill and Ross \cite{WeillRoss2004b}
40
define \ac{it} governance as representing ``the framework for decision
41
rights and accountabilities to encourage desirable behavior in the use
42
of \ac{it}''. This definition captures the high level at which \ac{it}
43
governance operates, but at the same time emphasises the unique
44
character it can attain since desirable behaviors differ between
45
organisations. It also encompasses both the behavioural and normative
46
aspects of governance in line with \ac{oecd} principles \cite{OECD}.
47

    
48
Relating \ac{it} governance with other aspects of the organisation,
49
Van Grembergen \cite{Grembergen2003} proposes the following
50
definition: ``\ac{it} governance is the organisational capacity
51
exercised by the board, executive management and \ac{it} management to
52
control the formulation and implementation of \ac{it} strategy and in
53
this way ensure the fusion of business and \ac{it}''. Along other
54
material operationally focused on implementation, the \ac{it}
55
Governance Institute suggests that ``\ac{it} Governance is the
56
responsibility of the Board of Directors and executive management. It
57
is an integral part of enterprise governance and consists of the
58
leadership and organisational structures and processes that ensure
59
that the organisation's \ac{it} sustains and extends the
60
organisation?s strategy and objectives''~\cite{ITGI2003} .
61
	
62
The last two definitions emphasise the relevance to corporate
63
governance, a recurring theme in the literature. Weill
64
\cite{Weill2004} suggests that ``good \ac{it} governance draws on
65
corporate governance principles to manage and use \ac{it} to achieve
66
corporate performance goals''. Other work states that due to the
67
growing reliance of organisations on \ac{it}, it is very difficult to
68
distinguish between \ac{it} and corporate governance, since they are
69
interrelated and constantly feeding into each other
70
\cite{Grembergen2003}. In addition to this synergy, the literature on
71
Strategic Information Systems Planning also provides useful guidance
72
to \ac{it} governance\cite{Webb2006}, as it contributes to work on its
73
supporting mechanisms such as critical success factors, the value
74
chain model and business process reengineering \cite{Grembergen2003}.
75

    
76
There is, however, a clear demarcation between \ac{it} governance and
77
\ac{it} management. The former is usually referred to as a broader
78
term that covers \ac{it} performance and transformation towards
79
business and customer demands, while the latter is restricted to
80
denoting effective supply of \ac{it} services and products, as well as
81
management of \ac{it} operations \cite{Peterson2003}. Although
82
scholars and practitioners insist on the value of involving \ac{it}
83
management in \ac{it} governance processes, they are quick to dismiss
84
the assumption of \ac{it} governance as an enhanced mode of \ac{it}
85
management and draw a definite line between the two concepts and the
86
distinct purposes they serve \cite{HaesGrembergen2004,Peterson2003}.
87
As Weill and Ross\cite{WeillRoss2004b} clearly explain, governance
88
establishes who has the right to make decisions, while management
89
involves the actual decision-making and implementation processes.
90

    
91
A large part of the literature discusses an extended view of \ac{it}
92
governance, departing from decision rights to include governance
93
mechanisms, informal arrangements and other means to support
94
organisational objectives, as will be discussed in the following
95
sections.
96

    
97
\section{Key IT Governance Decisions}
98
\label{sec:key-it-governance-decisions}
99

    
100
Weill and Ross \cite{WeillRoss2004b} depart from traditional research
101
on \ac{it} governance with their contemporary framework for the
102
customisation of \ac{it} governance systems \cite{BrownGrant2005}.
103
Drawing on research in 250 companies worldwide, they argue that the
104
starting point for effective \ac{it} governance lies in articulating
105
\ac{it} governance decisions and positioning the appropriate people to
106
engage in decision-making in the following five interrelated areas:
107
		
108
\begin{itemize}
109

    
110
\item \ac{it} Principles
111

    
112
  These are high-level statements regarding the use of \ac{it} and
113
  should be derived naturally to match and support an organisation's
114
  business and operational objectives. Weill and Ross
115
  \cite{WeillRoss2004b} suggest that these principles should identify
116
  the organisational operating model, concrete ways in which \ac{it}
117
  can support it, and the funding model required. \ac{it} principles
118
  guide decisions in the other domains listed below and may be used to
119
  raise a shared understanding among organisational members.
120

    
121
\item \ac{it} Architecture
122

    
123
  Architecture design relies on \ac{it} principles to capture
124
  requirements for process, data and technical standardisation and
125
  integration, according to the organisation's objectives. For
126
  example, the extent to which an organisation decides between stable
127
  infrastructure and local flexible applications reflects a
128
  translation of relevant strategic choices such as the degree of
129
  business flexibility.
130

    
131
\item \ac{it} Infrastructure Strategies 
132

    
133
  \ac{it} infrastructure is defined as ``the foundation of planned
134
  \ac{it} capability (both technical and human) available throughout
135
  the business as shared and reliable services and used by multiple
136
  applications''~\cite{WeillRoss2004b}. Examples of crucial governance
137
  decisions around infrastructure include the location of
138
  infrastructure services, pricing, updating and outsourcing.
139

    
140
\item Business Applications Needs
141

    
142
  Decisions in this area seek to achieve a balance between, on the one
143
  hand, finding creative ways to increase business value through
144
  applications that support organisational objectives and, on the
145
  other, complying with architectural integrity.
146

    
147
\item \ac{it} Investment and Prioritisation
148

    
149
  Investment levels should correspond to the strategic role attached
150
  to \ac{it}. An \ac{it} investment portfolio---an analogy to
151
  financial investment portfolios---provides a useful way to approach
152
  decisions on funding allocation, based on strategic alignment,
153
  return and risk considerations. Prioritising and reconciling \ac{it}
154
  needs between organisational departments, as well as distinguishing
155
  absolutely necessary from merely desirable \ac{it} capabilities, are
156
  both included in this area of decision-making.
157

    
158
\end{itemize}
159

    
160
\section{IT Governance Forms and Archetypes}
161

    
162
A large part of the literature discusses appropriate \ac{it}
163
governance decision-making structures for different areas in order to
164
maximise efficiency and return on investment.
165

    
166
One of the most common approaches distinguishes ``\ac{it}-related
167
authority patterns'' as centralised, decentralised, or federal
168
\cite{SambamurthyZmud1999}. \emph{Centralised} \ac{it} governance
169
grants decision rights to corporate stakeholders only. The
170
\emph{decentralised} mode assigns authority to either divisional
171
units, a mix of divisional units and line management actors, or in
172
very rare cases, just to line managers. The advantages of the first
173
include control over \ac{it} and a greater opportunity to realise
174
economies of scale, while the second model allows for greater
175
customisation and responsiveness \cite{BrownGrant2005}.
176

    
177
A \emph{federal} model would involve a corporate unit and divisional
178
units or line management in different variations \cite{Peterson2004,
179
  SambamurthyZmud1999, Weill2004}, combining the advantages of both
180
centralised and decentralised models. Peterson suggests a distinction
181
between \ac{it}-centric and business-centric approaches, according to
182
the participation of \ac{it} and business executives in
183
decision-making \cite{Peterson2004}. Typically, there is central
184
control on decisions around \ac{it} infrastructure supply and
185
decentralised patterns regarding \ac{it} applications and use
186
\cite{BrownMagill1998}. Similar types of \ac{it} governance have been
187
described as hybrid, distributed, centrally-decentralised and
188
equilibrium models or structures \cite{BrownGrant2005}.
189

    
190
Sambamurthy and Zmud \cite{SambamurthyZmud1999} note that \ac{it}
191
governance arrangements are not stable but frequently change from more
192
centralised to more decentralised forms and vice versa. At the same
193
time, it is acknowledged that there are no strict boundaries
194
between centralised, decentralised and federal models, since they are
195
all situated on a continuum and reflecting more complicated
196
arrangements encountered in organisations \cite{BrownGrant2005}.
197

    
198
In essence, governance structures are put in place to balance the
199
tensions between local units and central parts of an enterprise
200
\cite{Huang2010}. To achieve this task, more flexible \ac{it}
201
governance models have been developed, in vertically and horizontally
202
expanded variations \cite{BrownGrant2005, WeillRoss2004b}. Six \ac{it}
203
governance archetypes have been identified to illustrate which sets of
204
stakeholders have input and/or decision rights regarding the five key
205
decisions areas described in~\ref{sec:key-it-governance-decisions}.
206

    
207
\paragraph{Business Monarchy}
208
In business monarchies, business executives at the most senior levels
209
of organisations (CxOs) make decisions on \ac{it} governance. This
210
style is common with respect to \ac{it} principles, in this way
211
enhancing the chances for \ac{it} alignment with business objectives.
212
\ac{it} investment is another area of regular application, where such
213
high-level budgeting decisions establish funding priorities across
214
competing parts of the organisation, rather than being solely focused
215
on \ac{it}.
216

    
217
\paragraph{IT Monarchy}
218
Senior \ac{it} executives make decisions in groups or individually,
219
usually with input from both corporate teams and business units. This
220
governance model is more frequently adopted in \ac{it} architecture
221
and \ac{it} infrastructure strategies decisions. In other areas the
222
involvement of business executives is required to ensure strategically
223
important goals, responsibility and commitment.
224

    
225
\paragraph{Feudal}
226
Feudal arrangements delegate decision-making to the leaders of
227
business units, regions or business functions who own \ac{it}
228
processes. However, this is a less widespread model, as it does not
229
take advantage of synergies across the organisation. Only little
230
application has been observed.
231

    
232
\paragraph{Federal}
233
This model of \ac{it} governance involves coordination between the
234
senior business executives and business unit leaders. There is often
235
participation of senior \ac{it} executives or business unit \ac{it}
236
leaders. The federal archetype is regularly used, but only to provide
237
input to all five decision areas
238
of Section~\ref{sec:key-it-governance-decisions} by a large percentage of the
239
organisations studied. Actual decision-making is organised around this
240
type of arrangement mainly with regard to business applications needs
241
across different units, as well as for \ac{it} investment, in order to
242
ensure a balance between different business units' priorities. It can
243
be argued that this model favours large and powerful business units,
244
leading the rest to adopt local \ac{it} solutions.
245

    
246
\paragraph{IT Duopoly}
247
Duopolies refer to bilateral decision-making processes between \ac{it}
248
executives (only central or together with those from business units)
249
and either senior level business executives, or business unit leaders,
250
the same group involved in feudal arrangements. The simple management
251
structure and the ability to customise decisions for different units
252
efficiently make duopolies popular in the five key \ac{it} governance
253
decision areas. Regarding \ac{it} principles, coordination between
254
senior business and \ac{it} management ensures alignment and
255
commitment to business objectives. Duopolies allow rapid consideration
256
of both business and technological issues around shared infrastructure
257
services, transferring expertise from one party to the other.
258
Moreover, \ac{it} duopolies increase the involvement of \ac{it} in
259
business applications decisions, resulting to greater exploitation of
260
current technical infrastructures. Along these lines, \ac{it}
261
investment and prioritisation often relies on \ac{it} duopolies to
262
identify risks and opportunities, especially around long-term and more
263
efficient sharing of infrastructures.
264

    
265
\paragraph{Anarchy}
266
Here, there is no coordination across the organisation, as local needs
267
guide decisions made by individuals or small groups independently.
268
This model is very rare and only appropriate when it is necessary to
269
react quickly to change.
270

    
271
As organisations expand geographically and diversify their activities,
272
organisational structures are not adequate to reconcile conflicting
273
needs and objectives and \ac{it} governance becomes indispensable. A
274
certain amount of heterogeneity in governance forms archetypes is
275
identified across studies, while it is now widely acknowledged that
276
``there is no single `best' \ac{it} organisational structure or
277
governance arrangement because \ac{it} needs to respond to the unique
278
environment within which it exists'' \cite{Agarwal2002,
279
  BrownGrant2005}. Willson and Pollard stress the significance of the
280
unique characteristics of the organisational and historical
281
environment \cite{WillsonPollard2009}. Other research shows that more
282
successful organisations are adopting specific governance models
283
\cite{WeillRoss2004b}. A significant amount of work has been devoted
284
to understanding how specific variables affect \ac{it} governance
285
structures. This topic will be discussed in the following section.
286

    
287

    
288
\section{Drivers of IT Governance Forms: Multiple Contigencies}
289

    
290
It is important to understand the reasons for adopting specific
291
\ac{it} governance arrangements \cite{SambamurthyZmud1999}. Early
292
research considered single contingencies or a set of individual
293
contingencies without paying attention to possible interactions.
294
Strategic and performance goals, organisational and decision-making
295
structures, governance experience, size and diversity have been found
296
to influence the choice of \ac{it} governance structural forms
297
\cite{BrownGrant2005, WeillRoss2004b}. At the same time, differences
298
according to industries and regions determine appropriate governance
299
arrangements. For instance, not-for-profit and government
300
organisations are characterised by different performance measures,
301
accountability patterns and cultures; as a result, governance
302
archetypes suitable to successful for-profit companies may not apply
303
directly to these organisations.
304

    
305
In any case, single contingency factors are not adequate to explain
306
how \ac{it} governance forms are shaped, since there is significant
307
interaction between multiple influences \cite{BrownMagill1998,
308
  SambamurthyZmud1999}. A theory of multiple contingencies has been
309
introduced~\cite{SambamurthyZmud1999}, looking at how a consideration
310
of reinforcing, conflicting and dominating forces generates a better
311
understanding of the evolutionary nature of \ac{it} governance in
312
organisations. Through empirical work it was found that reinforcing
313
and dominating contingencies would contribute towards centralised or
314
decentralised models of \ac{it} governance, while conflicting
315
contingencies were more likely to create federal modes. Contingencies
316
have been grouped in three categories. These explain the establishment
317
of specific \ac{it} governance types against others.
318
	
319
\paragraph{Corporate Governance}
320
\ac{it} governance models frequently reflect similar arrangements
321
adopted in the corporate governance of the same organisations. In
322
addition, the size of the firm plays a significant role, as larger
323
organisations usually have more divisions and tend to decentralise
324
corporate and \ac{it} governance to be able to respond to the needs of
325
the business units.
326
	
327
\paragraph{Economies of Scope}
328
Economies of scope are defined as ``the benefits arising from the
329
sharing of appropriate \ac{it}-related expertise, know-how and
330
investments across the enterprise''~\cite{SambamurthyZmud1999}.
331
Drawing on strategic management literature, it is suggested that
332
diversification mode, diversification breadth, and exploitation
333
strategy are three additional factors influencing \ac{it} governance.
334
\begin{itemize}
335

    
336
\item \emph{Diversification mode} refers to whether, on the one hand,
337
  strategic goals towards growth assume an internal outlook,
338
  leveraging existing technological capabilities and infrastructures.
339
  A centralised mode would facilitate coordination of such objectives.
340
  On the other hand, the diversification mode can be directed towards
341
  external expansion through acquisitions, a strategy that may require
342
  a decentralised form of \ac{it} governance in order to accommodate
343
  differences between the \ac{it} infrastructures and units.
344

    
345
\item \emph{Diversification breadth} refers to the similarity between
346
  the products of different business units in the same firm or the
347
  relevance of the markets they compete in. Assuming that greater
348
  similarity in products and markets means less differentiation in
349
  \ac{it}, a centralised mode would be more likely to achieve
350
  economies of scope. Conversely, little similarity in products and
351
  markets would make a decentralised model more appropriate.
352

    
353
\item Under the condition that diversification mode or breadth allow
354
  the leveraging of economies of scope, \emph{exploitation strategies}
355
  provide an avenue to take further advantage of the situation. One
356
  way to achieve this would be either by building internal
357
  partnerships to integrate \ac{it} knowledge and authority, and
358
  thereby adopting decentralised \ac{it} governance at the divisional
359
  level, or by merging \ac{it} assets, supported by centralised
360
  decision rights. \end{itemize}
361

    
362
\paragraph{Absorptive Capacity}
363
This term is used to denote employee experience and capabilities in
364
evaluating information and constructing knowledge bases, as well as
365
engaging in effective decision-making and implementation. Lack of
366
\ac{it}-related absorptive capacity in line management favours
367
centralised \ac{it} governance models, while greater \ac{it}
368
experience supports decentralised forms.
369

    
370
\section{Governance Mechanisms} 
371

    
372
\ac{it} governance is not solely determined by governance
373
forms~\cite{Ribbers2002, Schwarz2003}, as these work within a dynamic
374
and competitive environment. In addition to decision rights and
375
authority structures, the \ac{it} governance literature extends to
376
examine horizontal integration capabilities, as ``the ability to
377
coordinate and integrate formal and informal \ac{it} decision-making
378
authority across business and \ac{it} stakeholder communities''
379
\cite{Peterson2004}. This section will discuss the cross-functional
380
implementation of \ac{it} governance in terms of formal and informal
381
coordination mechanisms, structural layers and processes
382
\cite{Brown2004}.
383

    
384
\paragraph{Structures and Committees}
385
	
386
Structures and committees are referred to as structural \ac{it}
387
governance capabilities \cite{Peterson2004}. Unrelated to \ac{it}
388
governance forms, these mechanisms involve formal roles and
389
relationships contributing to horizontal contact between \ac{it} and
390
business management. \acsp{cio} and liaison roles such as \ac{it}
391
relationship managers, \ac{it} account managers, as well as \ac{it}
392
executive councils and project committees, advisory boards and centres
393
of excellence, are all elements of structural capabilities.
394

    
395
Weill and Ross \cite{WeillRoss2004b} emphasise the decision-making
396
responsibilities accompanying this type of mechanisms, discuss how
397
they can generate commitment and relate these with the \ac{it}
398
governance archetypes. As it would be anticipated, business monarchies
399
employ executive committees or part of these, sometimes together with
400
the {\sc ceo}. In \ac{it} monarchies one encounters \ac{it}
401
leadership teams and \ac{it} architecture committees, with some
402
members participating in both the \ac{it} and business realms in order
403
to ensure alignment. The drive for shared \ac{it} infrastructures and
404
data makes federal archetypes necessary, but to balance local and
405
enterprise priorities, senior executive committees in this case draw
406
members from all business units. Duopolies are supported by three
407
mechanisms: \ac{it} councils with joint business/\ac{it} memberships,
408
process teams comprising cross-functional process owners and
409
\ac{it} executives, as well as business/\ac{it} relationship managers.
410
	
411
\paragraph{Processes and Control Frameworks}
412
	
413
This type of mechanism reflects the degree to which decision-making
414
and monitoring follow formalised standard procedures and rules
415
\cite{Peterson2004}. Apart from \ac{it} governance frameworks
416
developed by organisations themselves, there is a range of \ac{it}
417
standards provided by external bodies that consolidate best practices
418
in a structured manner, but at the same time allow organisations to
419
adapt them to their needs.
420

    
421
One of the most widely accepted frameworks is the \ac{cobit},
422
published free online by the \ac{isaca}. This set of guidance
423
documentation includes the framework, high-level and detailed control
424
objectives, audit guidelines, management guidelines and an
425
implementation guide together with a toolkit, to support executives
426
with \ac{it} governance \cite{COBIT, Guldentops2003}. De Haes and Van
427
Grembergen \cite{HaesGrembergen2004} suggest complementing \ac{cobit}
428
with the \ac{itil}, a framework maintained by the \ac{ogc} in the
429
United Kingdom. It is significantly oriented towards service
430
management, such as payroll infrastructures, and comprises of best
431
practice documentation material on strategy, design, transition,
432
operation and continual service improvement
433
(\url{http://www.itil-officialsite.com}).
434

    
435
Maturity models are also useful to benchmark performance and alignment
436
against other standards. Some maturity models are included in, for
437
instance the management guidelines of \ac{cobit}, or are developed
438
separately by researchers or institutions such as the \ac{it}
439
Governance Institute \cite{HaesGrembergen2004, Luftman2003}. Simonsson
440
et al \cite{Simonsson2010} carried out 35 case studies to examine the
441
correlation between \ac{it} governance maturity and \ac{it} governance
442
performance. The strongest positive correlation to \ac{it} governance
443
performance was exhibited by the internal \ac{it} structure, clear
444
organizational structures and relationships, mature quality management
445
and cost allocation. Minimal correlation was found with the maturity
446
of project management, service level management, performance and
447
capacity management.
448

    
449
Taking the view of \ac{it} as a service provider to the rest of the
450
organisation, the Balanced Scorecard can be used to control \ac{it}
451
performance in areas such as user satisfaction, business contribution,
452
operational excellence and future orientation
453
\cite{HaesGrembergen2004, Grembergen2000}. In addition, by linking the
454
objectives of the business Scorecard to the \ac{it} Scorecard, there
455
is greater strategic alignment and capability exploitation
456
\cite{HaesGrembergen2004, Grembergen2000}.
457

    
458
Other related measurement and control tools include Service Level
459
Agreements, strategic alignment frameworks and information economics
460
models \cite{HaesGrembergen2004, Karten2004, WeillRoss2004b}. Weill
461
and Ross add to these the \ac{it} investment approval process, the
462
architectural exception process, chargeback, project tracking and the
463
formal tracking of business value and benefit realisation
464
\cite{WeillRoss2004b}. A review of such \ac{it} governance tools can
465
be found in \cite{Larsen2006}. It should be noted though that these
466
tools cannot provide universal solutions, but need to be assessed and
467
adapted against the specific context of implementation. Learning
468
achieved through iterative modifications is of great significance
469
\cite{Weill2004}.
470
	
471
\paragraph{Relational Mechanisms}
472

    
473
Structures and committees, and processes and control frameworks, do
474
not guarantee effective \ac{it} governance \cite{Peterson2004}.
475
Organisations employ relational mechanisms to improve lateral
476
communication and understanding between corporate executives, \ac{it}
477
and business people \cite{HaesGrembergen2004}. The purpose is to find
478
integrative solutions combining expert and tacit knowledge through
479
participation and collaboration across boundaries. This type of
480
relational integration is facilitated through direct informal contacts
481
and negotiations, common locations and ``virtual meeting points'',
482
lobbying, joint performance incentives and shared learning
483
\cite{Peterson2004}.
484

    
485
Weill and Ross have focused on the communication aspect of relational
486
mechanisms \cite{WeillRoss2004b}. They have found that formal
487
communication of \ac{it} governance mechanisms relates to more
488
effective governance (while informal communication is not associated
489
with governance effectiveness). Some examples of such communication
490
devices include senior management announcements, communication between
491
and within formal committees to coordinate efforts, web-based portals
492
and intranets. Ownership in the sense of discussing \ac{it} governance
493
in the office of the \acs{cio} or a devoted \ac{it} governance office are
494
deemed equally important. Last but not least, a significant amount of
495
time is spent to guide managers through \ac{it} architecture in order
496
to increase acceptance and conformity to \ac{it} governance
497
arrangements.
498

    
499
Robbins proposes a more inclusive approach to \ac{it} governance,
500
involving external parties such as partners, service providers and
501
communities of practice \cite{Robbins2004}. In certain arrangements
502
such as outsourcing this outside input to decision-making is sought
503
regularly already \cite{WeillRoss2004b}.
504

    
505
\begin{table}
506
\caption{Structures, Processes and Relational Mechanisms \cite{HaesGrembergen2004, Grembergen2003, Peterson2004, WeillRoss2004b}}
507
\begin{center}
508
    	\begin{tabular}{ | p{2.5cm} | p{2cm} | p{2cm} | p{2,4cm} | p{2cm} |}
509
    	\hline
510
        & \textbf{Structures} & \textbf{Processes} & \multicolumn{2}{c|}{\textbf{Relational Mechanisms}} \\ \hline
511
  	
512
	\textbf{Tactics} & \ac{it} executives and accounts & Strategic \ac{it} decision-making & Stakeholder participation & Strategic dialog \\
513
	& Committees and councils & Strategic \ac{it} monitoring & Business / \ac{it} partnerships & Shared learning \\ \hline
514
	\textbf{Mechanisms} & Roles and responsibilities\medskip
515

    
516
	\ac{it} organisation structure\medskip
517
	
518
        \acs{cio} on board\medskip
519
	
520
        \ac{it} strategy committee\medskip
521

    
522
	\ac{it} steering committee & Strategic information systems planning\medskip
523

    
524
	Balanced (\ac{it}) scorecards\medskip
525

    
526
	Information economics\medskip
527

    
528
	Service level agreements\medskip
529

    
530
	\ac{cobit} and \ac{itil}\medskip
531

    
532
	\ac{it} alignment / governance maturity models & Active participation by principal stakeholders\medskip
533

    
534
	Collaboration between principal stakeholders\medskip
535

    
536
	Partnership rewards and incentives\medskip
537

    
538
	Business/\ac{it} colocation & Shared understanding of business/\ac{it} objectives\medskip
539

    
540
	Active conflict resolution\medskip
541
	
542
	Cross-functional business/\ac{it} training\medskip
543

    
544
	Cross-functional business/\ac{it} job rotation\\ \hline
545
     	\end{tabular}
546
\end{center}
547
\label{default}
548
\end{table}
549

    
550
The mechanisms mentioned above should be simple and unambiguous,
551
transparent and suitable to engage appropriate individuals. The design
552
of mechanisms should employ a mix of techniques from all three types
553
and implement these at multiple organisational levels, use less but
554
more effective decision-making structures focusing on alignment, while
555
overlapping membership and clear accountability patterns should be
556
considered \cite{WeillRoss2004b}.
557

    
558
\section{Effective Governance}
559

    
560
Weill and Ross suggest top for-profit governance performers have more
561
managers who are able to accurately describe the role of \ac{it}
562
governance in their organisation \cite{WeillRoss2004b}. Senior
563
management engages more effectively through structural, relational and
564
communication mechanisms. Objectives for \ac{it} investment are
565
clearly articulated and communicated, through generally stable \ac{it}
566
governance arrangements over time. They also observe more formal
567
architecture exception processes, together with diversified business
568
strategies.
569

    
570
High-level commitment and communication emerge as significant elements
571
of contemporary \ac{it} governance. Departing from an earlier focus on
572
loci of control, Peterson concludes that collaboration is the
573
foundation of effective \ac{it} governance, ``where the need for
574
distinct competencies is recognized, developed, and shared adaptively
575
across functional, organizational, cultural, and geographic
576
boundaries'' \cite{Peterson2004}.
577

    
578
%%% Local Variables: 
579
%%% mode: latex
580
%%% TeX-master: "governance"
581
%%% End: